PRINCETON – “Do I
have to go on my knees?” the International Monetary Fund’s managing director,
Christine Lagarde, asked the BBC’s Andrew Marr.
Lagarde was apologizing for the IMF’s poor forecasting of the United Kingdom’s
recent economic performance, and, more seriously, for the Fund’s
longer-standing criticism of the fiscal austerity pursued by Prime Minister
David Cameron’s government. Now endorsing British austerity, Lagarde said that
it had increased confidence in the UK’s economic prospects, thereby spurring
the recent recovery.
Lagarde’s apology
was unprecedented, courageous, and wrong. By issuing it, the IMF compromised on
an economic principle that enjoys overwhelming academic support: The confidence
“fairy” does not exist. And, by bowing to the UK’s pressure, the Fund
undermined its only real asset – its independence.
The IMF has dodged
responsibility for far more serious forecasting errors, including its failure
to anticipate every major crisis of the last generation, from Mexico in
1994-1995 to the near-collapse of the global financial system in 2008. Indeed,
in the 6-12 months prior to every crisis, the IMF’s forecasts implied business
as usual.
Some claim that
the Fund counsels countries in private, lest public warnings trigger the very
crisis that is to be avoided. But, with the possible exception of Thailand in
1997, the IMF’s long-time resident historian, James Boughton, finds little evidence for that view in internal
documents. The IMF’s Internal Evaluation Office is more directly scathing in its
assessment of the Fund’s obliviousness to the US subprime crisis as it emerged.Given that the IMF is the world’s anointed guardian of financial stability, its failure to warn and preempt constitutes a far more grievous lapse than its position on British austerity, with huge costs borne by many, especially the most vulnerable. For these failures, the Fund has never offered any apology, certainly not in the abject manner of Lagarde’s recent statement.
The Fund does well
to reflect on its errors. In a September 2003 speech in Kuala Lumpur,
then-Managing Director Horst Köhler conceded that temporary capital controls
can provide relief against volatile inflows from the rest of the world. He was
presumably acknowledging that the Fund had it wrong when it criticized Malaysia
for imposing such controls at the height of the Asian crisis. Among the
countries hurt by that crisis, Malaysia chose not to ask for the Fund’s help
and emerged at least as well as others that did seek IMF assistance.
Malaysia’s
imposition of capital controls was a controversial policy decision. And even as
the Fund opposed them, prominent economists – among them Paul Krugman – endorsed
their use. In his speech, Köhler reported that the Fund had taken the evidence
on board and would incorporate it in its future advice.
But in the current
crisis, the academic evidence has overwhelmingly shown that fiscal austerity
does what textbook economics says it will do: the more severe the austerity,
the greater the drag on growth. A variety of studies confirming this
proposition, including one by the IMF’s chief economist, Olivier
Blanchard, have withstood considerable scrutiny and leave little room for
ambiguity.
The two public
voices arguing for the magical properties of austerity are official agencies
based in Europe: the OECD and the European Commission. The Commission’s stance,
in particular, is animated by an institutional commitment to a fiscal viewpoint
that leaves no room for evidence.
Among the G-7
economies, only Italy has done worse than the UK since the Great Recession
began. Indeed, the UK’s GDP has only just regained its 2008 level,
lagging behind even France.
This is all the
more remarkable given that the crisis in the UK was comparatively mild. The
fall in property prices was modest relative to Ireland and Spain, and, because
there was no construction boom, there was no construction bust. Having missed
the warning signs about the bank Northern Rock, which needed to be bailed out
by the UK government after a run on its deposits in September 2007, the British
authorities, unlike their eurozone counterparts, quickly dealt with the
economy’s distressed banks. For these reasons, the UK should have had a quick
recovery; instead, the Cameron government’s gratuitous austerity stifled it.
The IMF’s apology
was a mistake for two reasons. Thumbing one’s nose at scholarly evidence is
always a bad idea, but it is especially damaging to an institution that relies
so heavily on the credibility of its technical competence and neutrality. If
the Fund embraces muddled economics, on what basis will it defend its policy
advice?
Moreover, in
choosing to flatter the UK’s misguided policy, the Fund has confirmed its
deference to its major shareholders. For years, the view has been that the IMF
is a foreign-policy instrument of the United States. The softness in its annual
surveillance of UK economic policy has also been well known.
But in taking this
latest step, the Fund has undermined – perhaps fatally – its ability to speak
“truth to power.” If so, a fundamental question may well become unavoidable:
Why does the IMF exist, and for whom?
Read more at http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/ashoka-mody-lambasts-the-fund-s-recent-apology-for-its-criticism-of-britain-s-austerity-policies#YDuoffjMc5RjYMba.99
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario